A Critique of Crisis Theory- a Socialist day school with Mike Treen
The following is based on talks given by Mike Treen, national director of the New Zealand Unite Union, at the annual conference of the socialist organisation Fightback, held in Wellington, May 31 - June 1, 2014, and a seminar hosted by Socialist Aotearoa in Auckland on October 12.
The National Business Review reported a comment by our Minister of Finance Bill English on August 15 that he had occasionally pointed out in speeches to business audiences that New Zealand has had post World War Two recessions roughly every 10 years: in 1957-58; 1967-68; the mid 1970s; the mid 1980s; 1997-98 and 2007-8. He would observe laconically: “You'd think we would see them coming”
But of course bourgeois economists, commentators and journalists don't generally see them coming. One problem, however, is that sometimes the Marxist alternative sees them coming a little too often.
But
it is a simple fact of life that capitalism has had
economic
crises on a periodic basis at least since 1825. Every 10 years or so,
capitalism goes through a cycle of boom and bust. The following charts for the US economy illustrate this reality.
Capitalism
also goes through historical periods where the
industrial cycles of boom and bust are more pronounced one way or
another. That
is, capitalism goes through periods of several decades such as the
post-World War II “Long Boom” involving multiple cycles where the
upturns are relatively stronger than the downturns.
Similarly
there are other periods such as the decades following the crisis of
1873 where the upward phases of the cycle are relatively weak and the
downward phases more pronounced.
Understanding
these cyclical fluctuations is also closely connected to another
element of Marxist theory that is important to explaining what is
happening —historical materialism – which is simply a way of
viewing and understanding history.
Human
societies, ever since we humans began generating a consistent
surplus, have been divided into classes where each class is defined
by its relationship to the means and mode of production. The legal,
political, social, and cultural elements of society arise from this
economic foundation.
The
relations and modes of production, which determine how the economic
system is produced and reproduced, have gone through various stages
as technology and the forces of production have advanced. The main
stages have been slavery, feudalism, capitalism and the beginning
efforts to construct socialism.
Economic
systems do not pass away until they have exhausted their progressive
functions in terms of increasing society's productive capacity, which
in turn enables population growth and cultural development. When the
growth of the productive forces reaches a certain limit within the
framework of the existing society, the question is posed: Can the
fetters of the existing social relations be thrown off and a new
society established?
Marx's
answers
Marx
devoted his life to answering this question in relationship to
capitalism. This was THE question from his point of view. Decades of
research, decades of writing, decades of reflection—in between
throwing himself into labour struggles and the odd revolution when
they were happening. But he always returned to this basic task.
The
key questions were understanding why capitalism operates the way it
does and whether capitalism is a historically limited system—whether
it will reach a limit and need to be superseded. Marx's answers are
to be found in his writings, especially his great work known as
“Capital”.
Our
inability, so far, to supersede capitalism on a world scale means
that periodic crises return again and again, each one causing great
hardship while giving a powerful impetus to the centralisation of
capital and the growth of monopoly domination.
The system's dependence on relentless expansion over time and its inherent drive to maximise profit rather than meet human needs means that we now face the incompatibility of this system with our coexistence with mother Earth.
That
has become an element of crisis theory in the broader
sense—demonstrating the increasing incompatibility between a
livable environment and the way the system is organised through
private property and ownership.
The crises, therefore, tend to get bigger, more prolonged, and more socially destabilising. I think we have entered with the 2007-08 world recession a new period like that.
But there is no final crisis in this system—other than a descent into nuclear war, or barbarism arising from the sort of ecological winter or runaway ecological collapse that capitalism appears to be preparing for us. Short of such a disastrous outcome, the system will continue to carry on with its booms and busts until it is overthrown and replaced.
That
can only be carried out by a conscious social and political force, by
a class that is not bound to the system by material interest. That is
why the working class is the only class that can overthrow this
system. It is the only class not bound by property and profit to its
perpetuation. It is the only class with the numbers and social power,
if organised, if conscious enough, to effect this outcome and bring
about real majority rule.
Marx's
challenge
The
problem faced by Marx was that the challenge he took on in his
writing of “Capital” was so daunting that all we got during his
lifetime was the first part of a planned six-part work.
Marx
published a Volume 1 which was part of his planned first volume in
several editions. Engels, using Marx's notebooks, produced what we
know of as Volumes 2 and 3 after Marx's death. Then there was the
“Theories of Surplus Value”—a part of a rough draft of a
history of economic thought. All of that was originally going to be
the first volume of the planned six-part project.
There were to be additional volumes on wage labour, the state, the world market and competition. The entire work was to culminate in the volume on the world market. It was there logically that crises were to be dealt with in a systematic way. Marx does not deal with crises except in scattered references, mostly in Volume 3 of “Capital” and in his correspondence.
Marx's method was to begin at the most abstract level before moving progressively to the more concrete. In “Capital” he begins with the abstract categories of the commodity and value and moves through to the formation of prices and the role of money and the market.
He
goes on to explain the origin of profit in surplus value and ties
this all in with the origin of capitalism in what he called
“primitive accumulation”. Systematic treatment of things like
exchange rates, world trade and so on were to come later.
There
was an added problem with what we know as Volume 2, published after
Marx's death. Volume 2 is actually more a volume about how capitalism
works rather than how it doesn't. Marx explains how capitalism must
be a system of expanded reproduction and he presents formulas to
prove that is how it must exist and in a sense how it can exist.
There
was a certain consternation and debate inside the socialist movement
when Volume 2 was published. The revolutionary ideas of Marx and
Engels were already under attack within German Social Democracy, the
German workers party at the time, which was led by followers of Marx
and Engels. Volume 2 was used by critics of these revolutionary ideas
to “prove” that capitalism worked and could last indefinitely—in
support of the views of the reformist wing of German Social Democracy
led by Eduard Bernstein.
Because
the cause of crises wasn't fully spelt out in Marx and Engels' work,
revolutionaries like Rosa Luxemburg started to look for explanations
for why crises happen that didn't quite fit in with the logic of what
Marx and Engels had written. She looked at the exhaustion of the
world market. Others looked at things like the tendency of the rate
of profit to fall, which was viewed as a long-term historical
tendency by Marx.
This
logic can be deduced not only from their major economic works but
also from their journalism and correspondence where they wrote about
and analysed actual crises until Marx's death in 1883 and Engels' in
1895.
Capitalism
has also changed significantly since Marx and Engels wrote. These
changes need to be incorporated into our understanding of crises. The
system has evolved from industrial capitalism based on free
competition to monopoly capitalism.
We have been through the Great Depression of the 1930s. We have had the experience of the “Keynesian revolution”. We have had the Friedmanite counter-revolution and the debates in economic theory around that.
We
have had an end of the international gold standard, a very important
event. We had the stagflation of the 1970s, and the neoliberal turn
in the 1980s, which continues.
Most
recently, we have had the global “Great Recession” of 2007-2009,
followed by an unprecedentedly weak recovery, anaemic at best for most
of the world.
We can expect to be going into a new downturn in a few years' time, which could turn out to be even worse than the last crisis.
Conflicting
crisis theories
Marx
had identified the essence of the periodic crises of capitalism as
crises
of overproduction
very early on, even in the Communist Manifesto in 1848.
I am emphasising this because there has been a retreat from this analysis including among followers of Marx. In fact the two main schools of Marxist crisis theory today are not schools based on periodic overproduction crises.
One
school is based around the primacy of the tendency of the rate of
profit to fall (TROPF). Marx introduced this idea in Volume 3 of
“Capital” as an important long-term historical tendency in
capitalism. Marx also pointed out many counter tendencies, but over
long periods the tendency is true. Many Marxist economists use that
important theory as the primary explanation for why capitalism has
crises.
This
school of thought is associated with the US academic Andrew Kliman,
and British theorists from the Trotskyist tradition including the
British SWP leader Alex Callinicos and the prolific blogger Michael
Roberts. All three writers deserve to be read, and there is much to
learn from their writings.
But
the almost monomaniacal attachment to the TROPF to explain crises
leads them astray.
Michael
Roberts even tries to explain the 10-year cycle under capitalism as a
result of the fall in the rate of profit. It is of course true that
every crisis is associated with a fall in the rate of profit, but
that temporary decline is a result of the crisis not the cause.
Callinicos seems to deny the real growth of capitalism since the 1980s. Because the early 1980s crisis must have been the result of the TROPF, and since there has been no counter tendency big enough to overcome the falling rate of profit sufficiently, the crisis must be permanent. However, the world economy has more than doubled in size in that period, and we have seen an explosive growth in capitalist production in China.
The
other significant school of thought is associated with the US Monthly
Review magazine and its editor John Bellamy Foster. Foster is an
important writer on economic matters for the magazine as well as
being a leading theorist on the relevance of Marxism to understanding
the ecological challenges of today. The Monthly Review school is very
influenced by Keynesian ideas. John Maynard Keynes was a
pro-capitalist economist who became very influential in the wake of
the Great Depression of the 1930s.
Traditional
bourgeois economic theory denied that capitalism could have crises.
Keynes, looking at the crisis of the 1930s was forced to acknowledge
the reality staring him in the face – that capitalism can have
crises and in fact it seemed to him to have a tendency towards
stagnation But he believed the state could intervene to greatly
alleviate crises if not eliminate them altogether.
So
from a Keynesian point of view you do not have a crisis of
overproduction relative to monetarily effective demand, determined
ultimately by the existing size and rate of growth of the global
hoard of the money commodity—gold.
Rather, with Keynes you have a crisis of under-consumption that can be resolved by the state stepping in to purchase goods directly or printing money to give people to spend themselves and/or using government deficit spending to put more money into the economy. Part of the reason Keynes favoured ending he gold standard was to allow this to happen more easily.
Overproduction
as the underlying cause of crisis which is based on Marx's concept of
money as the universal equivalent has been, especially since the end
of what remained of the international gold standard in 1971, all but
forgotten including by most of those claiming to be Marxist.
System requires measure of value that is itself a commodity
A
central part of Marx's perfected labour theory of value was that it
requires—as does commodity production as a system—a measure of
value that is itself a commodity.
Ultimately, gold emerged as the main money commodity because it is durable, contains significant value (amount of abstract human labour measured in units of time) in a small quantity, and is easily divisible. It can only be a measure of value, however, because it has value as a product of labour itself, measured by its monetary use value in units of weight.
The
pro-capitalist alternative to that theory, as well as to Keynesian
under-consumptionism, is dubbed Say's Law—an economic principle of
early “vulgar” economics named after the French businessman and
economist Jean-Baptiste Say (1767–1832). Marx dubbed them “vulgar”
economists because they had ceased to seek a scientific explanation
for what was happening and instead provided simple apologies for
capitalism and its laws.
Say
stated that production creates its own demand. Commodities are bought
with commodities. Money plays no particular role except as an
intermediary.
This idea, combined with marginalism—the theory that commodities have exchange value because of their scarcity relative to human needs—tries to banish the labour theory of value by claiming things have value due to their marginal utility and that generalised overproduction of commodities is impossible.
Essentially,
this is a subjective rather than objective theory of value.
Marginalism, which assumes Say's Law either explicitly or implicitly,
was the end of bourgeois economics as any form of science. All
bourgeois economics today is built on these two theories and can't
escape them.
The
abolition of the gold standard has created very
real problems with the modern US dollar-based international monetary
system, with permanent inflation, regular exchange rate crises and
so on. Following the Bretton Woods monetary conference in 1944 up to
1971 when Nixon took the dollar off the gold standard money in
everyday use nearly always had a legally fixed relationship to gold
via the US dollar.
You
could go to a central bank and demand a certain amount of dollars for
your currency, which in turn would represent a specific amount of
gold, backed by the bullion hoard in Fort Knox.
Prior
to 1933, individuals as well as countries could demand gold for their
paper U.S. dollars. After 1933, up to 1971, foreign governments and
their central banks—but not individuals—could do the same.
But after the gold standard was completely abandoned, there was an assumption on the part of many Marxist economists that maybe Keynes was right on one point. Maybe now you could just create money at will. The state had the power not just to create tokens representing gold but create currency at will with no relationship to gold—now supposedly “just another commodity” like all others with no special role..
A
big mistake
I
think that is a big mistake. Ultimately, all non-commodity money—that
is, token money and credit money—must have a relationship to a real
money commodity like gold. This is true whether a formal gold
standard exists or not. This lawful economic relationship still
exists and therefore continues to be the underlying cause of crises
of overproduction.
When
they started to print money at will, in the 1970s, when Nixon said,
“We are all Keynesians now”, what you ended up with was a severe
bout of inflation as printed money lost value and lost its fixed
relationship to the money commodity, which remained gold.
The
“price” of gold surged—that is, it took more and more tokens to
represent the same amount of gold. Monetary tokens were being
devalued, and inflation was the inevitable result.
Engels (and Marx) on overproduction crises
The
nature of a crisis as an overproduction crisis was spelt out by
Engels in 1873.
Engels
was a remarkable man. He worked managing his family business in
Manchester for some decades operating as a capitalist in the textile
trade. He did that so he could keep his friend and intellectual
partner free to work on “Capital”. He hated what he did.
Engels
was a brilliant man but he knew there was one person—Karl Marx—who
alone at that time was both willing and able to carry through the
critique of bourgeois political economy. Engels was willing to do
whatever was necessary to enable Marx to work. The correspondence of
Marx and Engels is extraordinarily rich in political and economic
analysis.
Engels begged Marx to get on with the task of writing the book. Marx promised again and again that it was just around the corner. There came a certain point in his life when Engels could give the business up, and there is a wonderful letter where he expressed his joy at being liberated from his role as an industrial capitalist.
Engels
did a lot of writing in defence of the joint views of Marx and
Engels. On of his major works was a polemical work in 1877 called
“Anti-Duhring” against a then fashionable but now obscure German
professor that became an exposition of the mature views of Marx and
Engels on a broad range of political, historical, philosophical, and
economic ideas.
By
this time, all of Marx's major economic concepts had been developed.
He even wrote a chapter of “Anti-Duhring” himself. For those
attached to the TROPF it is not mentioned once as a cause of crisis.
However they did write an important paragraph summarising their joint
views on the origin of crises under capitalism. It reads:
We
have seen that the ever-increasing perfectibility of modern machinery
is, by the anarchy of social production, turned into a compulsory law
that forces the individual industrial capitalist always to improve
his machinery, always to increase its productive force.
The
bare possibility of extending the field of production is transformed
for him into a similarly compulsory law.
The
enormous expansive force of modern industry, compared with which that
of gases is mere child’s play, appears to us now as a necessity for
expansion, both qualitative and quantitative, that laughs at all
resistance.
Such
resistance is offered by consumption, by sales, by the markets for
the products of modern industry.
But
the capacity for extension, extensive and intensive, of the markets
is primarily governed by quite different laws that work much less
energetically. (Emphasis added)
The
extension of the markets cannot keep pace with the extension of
production.
The
collision becomes inevitable, and as this cannot produce any real
solution so long as it does not break in pieces the capitalist mode
of production, the collisions become periodic.
Capitalist
production has begotten another ‘vicious circle’.
The
problem is Engels didn't spell out what
these laws are that govern the capacity for growth
of the markets and why they work much less energetically.
But he spells out that he see the cycles of capitalism and the crises they produce as a periodic collision of two counterposed forces—the physical ability of capitalism to use modern science and technology to expand production without limit, and the different, less energetic laws governing the growth of the markets.
Laws governing growth of markets
The
laws that govern the growth of markets are connected to the role of
the money commodity as a measure of value and periodic changes in the
relative profitability of gold production versus the production of
other commodities.
Gold is both the universal equivalent, the measure of value, and a commodity in its own right. Therefore its production remains key to understanding the laws of capitalism that determine value, price and profit.
But
if you look at the history of capitalism there is a peculiarity about
gold, because it is the ultimate measure of value, that production of
gold tends to move counter cyclically to overall commodity
production. So when there is an overall boom in production in society
gold production tends to decline and during overall depressions in
society, gold production tends to increase. This is an important
mechanism for regulating capitalism.
As
prices in gold terms (in weights of gold) rise during the rising
phase of the industrial cycle, gold's purchasing power falls, gold
production becomes relatively less profitable, and capital flows out
of that sector, gold production slows, interest rates rise as money
becomes tight, and the boom ends in a crash.
When
prices in gold terms fall sharply in a crisis, gold's purchasing
power rises, gold production becomes relatively more profitable, and
capital flows into the sector causing gold production to rise, adding
to the growing idle money hoard resulting from the crisis itself,
pushing down interest rates, and the economy recovers.
The
capitalist system seeks to escape the limits of monetarily effective
demand by, as Marx explained some 150 years ago, expanding credit.
But credit cannot, even with all the miracles performed by modern
computers today, expand forever. In the end, the debt must be
serviced—interest and principle paid—and eventually the game is
up. Interest rates rise during the boom (overproduction) phase of the
industrial cycle, credit collapses and another crisis is born.
'Critique
of Crisis Theory' blog
In
the last two years or so, I have been working with a small group of
Marxists in North America who are doing a blog focused on economics
that I highly recommend.
It
is called “A
Critique of Crisis Theory”. What I have been explaining are
essentially their ideas.
The
first 40 or so posts of the blog are being turned into the draft of a
book. The author of the blog, Sam Williams, and his collaborators
have been working on their economic ideas for some decades. The
creation of the Internet has allowed these ideas to be shared with a
much wider audience than was possible before.
More
recently, Williams has been responding to new developments and
discussing with others who have engaged or critiqued his ideas.
I
tried to critique his views on an aspect of economic theory I thought
I had some familiarity with—productive and unproductive labour.
Classical
economists and Marx recognised that not all labour performed was
productive of value and surplus value. We can see this easily when we
look at the “labour” of a policeman, priest or soldier versus the
labour of a miner or factory worker. I think we can identify who is a
productive worker in that picture.
It
gets a more complicated when we look at the labour of bank workers
and retail workers whose labour may or may not be necessary for
production to occur. It gets even more complicated when we look at
workers in health and education who may be employed in a private
business producing a profit for the capitalist. Anyway that is the
area I wanted to discuss.
Sam
was patient in his responses and took the time to respond to my first
questions in a very pedagogical way.
Then
when I wrote back still disagreeing, he wrote an even longer and more
thorough response that included a reference to Einstein, who, he
said, proved that matter and energy are different forms of the same
thing, just as physical goods and “non-material” services can
both be commodities embodying labour value. That sealed the issue for
me and I conceded that they had a far better understanding on this
issue.
What I found by following the blog was that it appeared to answer many of the questions and doubts I had from my own reading of Marxist economic theory which has been an interest of mine though I am no “expert” which I will come back to. From a young age I had been very interested in Marxist economic theory. Initially I had been quite strongly influenced by a prominent Belgian Marxist economist by the name of Ernest Mandel. Much of what he wrote remains useful.
Mandel
hints at the continuing importance of the role of gold as the money
commodity in some things he wrote in the 1970s. He played an
important role in analysing the “long waves” of 40 or 50 years'
duration that appear to be a feature of capitalism, which I believe
is correct.
The
Critique blog author also believes long waves play an important role
and provides an explanation for a long cycle based on long-term
swings in gold production, which makes the argument for its
importance even more powerful.
Another
fine economist (Anwar Shaikh) who knows his Marx and supports an
understanding of the history of capitalism involving long waves has
produced a graph that supports the Critique of crisis theory on this
point. He follows the long term movement of wholesale prices in the
Us and the UK.
He
shows in his graph that there is a movement in wholesale prices
upwards during a period of the long wave that is dominated by strong
upturns in the business cycles and trend downward in prices during a
period of the long wave where business cycles are dominated by the
downward phase of the cycle. The decline in wholesale prices is
associated with a period of stagnation or long depression under
capitalism. So we have the 1873-1893 decline, the Great Depression of
1929-1939, the Great Stagflation of 1967-1982 and a similar decline
which he argues indicates a new Great Depression beginning in 2008.
To
produce an accurate version of the graph he needed to measure the
prices in terms of gold since in the period since the abolition of
the gold standard there has been a permanent inflation in paper money
prices that hides the real movement of prices in gold terms
This
fits very closely with the Critique of Crisis Theory blogs view. This
is summarised well in a recent blog which argues that:
As the production of money material declines, the quantity of money grows at an increasingly slow rate relative to real capital—productive and commodity capital. As a result, credit increasingly replaces money, eventually stretching the credit system to its limits.
Money
becomes tight and interest rates rise. This situation, assuming
capitalist production is retained, can only be resolved by a crash or
a series of crises and associated depressions of greater than average
intensity, duration, or both.
One
result of a crisis or series of crises of greater than usual violence
or duration is a lowering of the general price level—measured in
terms of the use value of gold bullion—once again to below the
value of commodities. This makes gold production and refining
industries more profitable than most other industries.
Capital
once again flows into gold mining and refining, causing the
production of gold bullion to rise once again. The quantity of money
then expands with low interest rates and “easy money.”
As
the process of liquidating the previous overproduction goes on,
especially of those commodities that serve as means of production,
the accumulation of (real) capital stagnates. As a result, for a
period of time, money capital is accumulated at a faster rate than
real capital.
But
once the accumulated overproduction—especially in the form of
surplus productive capacity—is liquidated, a new “sudden
expansion of the market” occurs leading to a series of industrial
cycles dominated by the boom phases rather than the crisis or
depression phases.
This
“long cycle” is built into the commodity foundation of capitalist
production and is the inevitable result of the commodity form itself
once it is fully developed.
But
this cycle is also affected by accidental events such as discoveries
of rich new gold mines and technological improvements in gold mining
or refining that can either weaken or reinforce it depending on
circumstances, as well as by such “accidents” as wars and
revolutions.
So history is not an automatic repetition of cycles but a complex process involving both chance and necessity.
Williams
and his collaborators are very orthodox in demanding a return to Marx
on the nature of capitalist crises as crises of the general
overproduction of commodities, as well as incorporating major
developments of the capitalist system in the 150 years since Marx and
Engels wrote and incorporating it into a better way of explaining
what is happening today.
An
important contribution
The
Critique of Crisis Theory blog is making an important contribution to
Marxist economic theory today. The blog is getting thousands of page
views a month and becoming influential in Marxist economic debates.
It is getting the recognition and respect it deserves.
The
world reality we face today is conforming to the central theses of
the blog. The 2007-2009 crisis more than any since the 1930s was
clearly a global crisis of overproduction. There were simply too many
houses, too many cars and so on. Of course “too many” from the
point of view of being “too many” to be sold for a profit not in
terms of human need.
Can't
leave it to 'experts'
I
think we all should pay respect to the founders of scientific
socialism and give this issue of crisis theory the attention and
importance it deserves. We cannot leave it to others, to so-called
experts.
I am not an “expert” on this stuff. It has been a continuing interest of mine, because it is important that we understand it and because it is important we understand who we are, what our role is, what we expect will happen to this system, who the agent of social change is going to be, and what the prospects are for making that happen in the world today. Those are all issues we can begin to address.

Comments